11.3: Monopoly Production and Pricing Decisions and Profit Outcome (2024)

  1. Last updated
  2. Save as PDF
  • Page ID
    3500
    • 11.3: Monopoly Production and Pricing Decisions and Profit Outcome (1)
    • Boundless
    • Boundless

    \( \newcommand{\vecs}[1]{\overset { \scriptstyle \rightharpoonup} {\mathbf{#1}}}\) \( \newcommand{\vecd}[1]{\overset{-\!-\!\rightharpoonup}{\vphantom{a}\smash{#1}}} \)\(\newcommand{\id}{\mathrm{id}}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\) \( \newcommand{\kernel}{\mathrm{null}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\range}{\mathrm{range}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\RealPart}{\mathrm{Re}}\) \( \newcommand{\ImaginaryPart}{\mathrm{Im}}\) \( \newcommand{\Argument}{\mathrm{Arg}}\) \( \newcommand{\norm}[1]{\| #1 \|}\) \( \newcommand{\inner}[2]{\langle #1, #2 \rangle}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\) \(\newcommand{\id}{\mathrm{id}}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\) \( \newcommand{\kernel}{\mathrm{null}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\range}{\mathrm{range}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\RealPart}{\mathrm{Re}}\) \( \newcommand{\ImaginaryPart}{\mathrm{Im}}\) \( \newcommand{\Argument}{\mathrm{Arg}}\) \( \newcommand{\norm}[1]{\| #1 \|}\) \( \newcommand{\inner}[2]{\langle #1, #2 \rangle}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\)\(\newcommand{\AA}{\unicode[.8,0]{x212B}}\)

    Market Differences Between Monopoly and Perfect Competition

    Monopolies, as opposed to perfectly competitive markets, have high barriers to entry and a single producer that acts as a price maker.

    learning objectives

    • Distinguish between monopolies and competitive firms

    A market can be structured differently depending on the characteristics of competition within that market. At one extreme is perfect competition. In a perfectly competitive market, there are many producers and consumers, no barriers to enter and exit the market, perfectly hom*ogeneous goods, perfect information, and well-defined property rights. This produces a system in which no individual economic actor can affect the price of a good – in other words, producers are price takers that can choose how much to produce, but not the price at which they can sell their output. In reality there are few industries that are truly perfectly competitive, but some come very close. For example, commodity markets (such as coal or copper) typically have many buyers and multiple sellers. There are few differences in quality between providers so goods can be easily substituted, and the goods are simple enough that both buyers and sellers have full information about the transaction. It is unlikely that a copper producer could raise their prices above the market rate and still find a buyer for their product, so sellers are price takers.

    A monopoly, on the other hand, exists when there is only one producer and many consumers. Monopolies are characterized by a lack of economic competition to produce the good or service and a lack of viable substitute goods. As a result, the single producer has control over the price of a good – in other words, the producer is a price maker that can determine the price level by deciding what quantity of a good to produce. Public utility companies tend to be monopolies. In the case of electricity distribution, for example, the cost to put up power lines is so high it is inefficient to have more than one provider. There are no good substitutes for electricity delivery so consumers have few options. If the electricity distributor decided to raise their prices it is likely that most consumers would continue to purchase electricity, so the seller is a price maker.

    11.3: Monopoly Production and Pricing Decisions and Profit Outcome (2)

    Electricity Distribution: The cost of electrical infrastructure is so expensive that there are few or no competitors for electricity distribution. This creates a monopoly.

    Sources of Monopoly Power

    Monopoly power comes from markets that have high barriers to entry. This can be caused by a variety of factors:

    • Increasing returns to scale over a large range of production
    • High capital requirements or large research and development costs
    • Production requires control over natural resources
    • Legal or regulatory barriers to entry
    • The presence of a network externality – that is, the use of a product by a person increases the value of that product for other people

    Monopoly Vs. Perfect Competition

    Monopoly and perfect competition mark the two extremes of market structures, but there are some similarities between firms in a perfectly competitive market and monopoly firms. Both face the same cost and production functions, and both seek to maximize profit. The shutdown decisions are the same, and both are assumed to have perfectly competitive factors markets.

    However, there are several key distinctions. In a perfectly competitive market, price equals marginal cost and firms earn an economic profit of zero. In a monopoly, the price is set above marginal cost and the firm earns a positive economic profit. Perfect competition produces an equilibrium in which the price and quantity of a good is economically efficient. Monopolies produce an equilibrium at which the price of a good is higher, and the quantity lower, than is economically efficient. For this reason, governments often seek to regulate monopolies and encourage increased competition.

    Marginal Revenue and Marginal Cost Relationship for Monopoly Production

    For monopolies, marginal cost curves are upward sloping and marginal revenues are downward sloping.

    learning objectives

    • Analyze how marginal and marginal costs affect a company’s production decision

    Profit Maximization

    In traditional economics, the goal of a firm is to maximize their profits. This means they want to maximize the difference between their earnings, i.e. revenue, and their spending, i.e. costs. To find the profit maximizing point, firms look at marginal revenue (MR) – the total additional revenue from selling one additional unit of output – and the marginal cost (MC) – the total additional cost of producing one additional unit of output. When the marginal revenue of selling a good is greater than the marginal cost of producing it, firms are making a profit on that product. This leads directly into the marginal decision rule, which dictates that a given good should continue to be produced if the marginal revenue of one unit is greater than its marginal cost. Therefore, the maximizing solution involves setting marginal revenue equal to marginal cost.

    This is relatively straightforward for firms in perfectly competitive markets, in which marginal revenue is the same as price. Monopoly production, however, is complicated by the fact that monopolies have demand curves and MR curves that are distinct, causing price to differ from marginal revenue.

    11.3: Monopoly Production and Pricing Decisions and Profit Outcome (3)

    Monopoly: In a monopoly market, the marginal revenue curve and the demand curve are distinct and downward-sloping. Production occurs where marginal cost and marginal revenue intersect.

    11.3: Monopoly Production and Pricing Decisions and Profit Outcome (4)

    Perfect Competition: In a perfectly competitive market, the marginal revenue curve is horizontal and equal to demand, or price. Production occurs where marginal cost and marginal revenue intersect.

    Monopoly Profit Maximization

    The marginal cost curves faced by monopolies are similar to those faced by perfectly competitive firms. Most will have low marginal costs at low levels of production, reflecting the fact that firms can take advantage of efficiency opportunities as they begin to grow. Marginal costs get higher as output increases. For example, a pizza restaurant can easily double production from one pizza per hour to two without hiring additional employees or buying more sophisticated equipment. When production reaches 50 pizzas per hour, however, it may be difficult to grow without investing a lot of money in more skilled employees or more high-tech ovens. This trend is reflected in the upward-sloping portion of the marginal cost curve.

    The marginal revenue curve for monopolies, however, is quite different than the marginal revenue curve for competitive firms. While competitive firms experience marginal revenue that is equal to price – represented graphically by a horizontal line – monopolies have downward-sloping marginal revenue curves that are different than the good’s price.

    Profit Maximization Function for Monopolies

    Monopolies set marginal cost equal to marginal revenue in order to maximize profit.

    learning objectives

    • Explain the monopolist’s profit maximization function

    Monopolies have much more power than firms normally would in competitive markets, but they still face limits determined by demand for a product. Higher prices (except under the most extreme conditions) mean lower sales. Therefore, monopolies must make a decision about where to set their price and the quantity of their supply to maximize profits. They can either choose their price, or they can choose the quantity that they will produce and allow market demand to set the price.

    Since costs are a function of quantity, the formula for profit maximization is written in terms of quantity rather than in price. The monopoly’s profits are given by the following equation:

    \[π=p(q)q−c(q)\]

    In this formula, p(q) is the price level at quantity q. The cost to the firm at quantity q is equal to c(q). Profits are represented by π. Since revenue is represented by pq and cost is c, profit is the difference between these two numbers. As a result, the first-order condition for maximizing profits at quantity q is represented by:

    \[0=∂q=p(q)+qp′(q)−c′(q)\]

    The above first-order condition must always be true if the firm is maximizing its profit – that is, if \(p(q)+qp′(q)−c′(q)\) is not equal to zero, then the firm can change its price or quantity and make more profit.

    Marginal revenue is calculated by \(p(q)+qp′(q)\), which is derived from the term for revenue, \(pq\). The term \(c′(q)\) is marginal cost, which is the derivative of c(q). Monopolies will produce at quantity q where marginal revenue equals marginal cost. Then they will charge the maximum price \(p(q)\) that market demand will respond to at that quantity.

    Consider the example of a monopoly firm that can produce widgets at a cost given by the following function:

    \[c(q)=2+3q+q^2\]

    If the firm produces two widgets, for example, the total cost is \(2+3(2)+2^2=12\). The price of widgets is determined by demand:

    \[p(q)=24-2p\]

    When the firm produces two widgets it can charge a price of \(24-2(2)=20\) for each widget. The firm’s profit, as shown above, is equal to the difference between the quantity produces multiplied by the price, and the total cost of production: \(p(q)q−c(q)\). How can we maximize this function?

    Using the first order condition, we know that when profit is maximized, \(0=p(q)+qp′(q)−c′(q)\). In this case:

    \[0=(24-2p)+q(-2)-(3+2q)=21-6q\]

    Rearranging the equation shows that \(q=3.5\). This is the profit maximizing quantity of production.

    Consider the diagram illustrating monopoly competition. The key points of this diagram are fivefold.

    1. First, marginal revenue lies below the demand curve. This occurs because marginal revenue is the demand, p(q), plus a negative number.
    2. Second, the monopoly quantity equates marginal revenue and marginal cost, but the monopoly price is higher than the marginal cost.
    3. Third, there is a deadweight loss, for the same reason that taxes create a deadweight loss: The higher price of the monopoly prevents some units from being traded that are valued more highly than they cost.
    4. Fourth, the monopoly profits from the increase in price, and the monopoly profit is illustrated.
    5. Fifth, since—under competitive conditions—supply equals marginal cost, the intersection of marginal cost and demand corresponds to the competitive outcome.

    We see that the monopoly restricts output and charges a higher price than would prevail under competition.

    11.3: Monopoly Production and Pricing Decisions and Profit Outcome (5)

    Monopoly Diagram: This graph illustrates the price and quantity of the market equilibrium under a monopoly.

    Monopoly Production Decision

    To maximize output, monopolies produce the quantity at which marginal supply is equal to marginal cost.

    learning objectives

    • Explain how to identify the monopolist’s production point

    Monopoly Production

    A pure monopoly has the same economic goal of perfectly competitive companies – to maximize profit. If we assume increasing marginal costs and exogenous input prices, the optimal decision for all firms is to equate the marginal cost and marginal revenue of production. Nonetheless, a pure monopoly can – unlike a firm in a competitive market – alter the market price for its own convenience: a decrease of production results in a higher price. Because of this, rather than finding the point where the marginal cost curve intersects a horizontal marginal revenue curve (which is equivalent to good’s price), we must find the point where the marginal cost curve intersect a downward-sloping marginal revenue curve.

    Monopoly Production Point

    Like non-monopolies, monopolists will produce the at the quantity such that marginal revenue (MR) equals marginal cost (MC). However, monopolists have the ability to change the market price based on the amount they produce since they are the only source of products in the market. When a monopolist produces the quantity determined by the intersection of MR and MC, it can charge the price determined by the market demand curve at the quantity. Therefore, monopolists produce less but charge more than a firm in a competitive market.

    11.3: Monopoly Production and Pricing Decisions and Profit Outcome (6)

    Monopoly Production: Monopolies produce at the point where marginal revenue equals marginal costs, but charge the price expressed on the market demand curve for that quantity of production.

    In short, three steps can determine a monopoly firm’s profit-maximizing price and output:

    1. Calculate and graph the firm’s marginal revenue, marginal cost, and demand curves
    2. Identify the point at which the marginal revenue and marginal cost curves intersect and determine the level of output at that point
    3. Use the demand curve to find the price that can be charged at that level of output

    Monopoly Price and Profit

    Monopolies can influence a good’s price by changing output levels, which allows them to make an economic profit.

    learning objectives

    • Analyze the final price and resulting profit for a monopolist

    Monopolies, unlike perfectly competitive firms, are able to influence the price of a good and are able to make a positive economic profit. While a perfectly competitive firm faces a single market price, represented by a horizontal demand/marginal revenue curve, a monopoly has the market all to itself and faces the downward-sloping market demand curve. An important consequence is worth noticing: typically a monopoly selects a higher price and lesser quantity of output than a price-taking company; again, less is available at a higher price.

    Imagine that the market demand for widgets is \(Q=30-2P\). This says that when the price is one, the market will demand 28 widgets; when the price is two, the market will demand 26 widgets; and so on. The monopoly’s total revenue is equal to the price of the widget multiplied by the quantity sold: \(P(30-2P)\). This can also be rearranged so that it is written in terms of quantity: total revenue equals \(Q(30-Q)/2\).

    The firm can produce widgets at a total cost of \(2Q^2\), that is, it can produce one widget for $2, two widgets for $8, three widgets for $18, and so on. We know that all firms maximize profit by setting marginal costs equal to marginal revenue. Finding this point requires taking the derivative of total revenue and total cost in terms of quantity and setting the two derivatives equal to each other. In this case:

    \[\dfrac{dTR}{dQ}=\dfrac{(30−2Q)}{2}\]

    \[\dfrac{dTC}{dQ}=4Q\]

    Setting these equal to each other: \(15−Q=4Q\)

    So the profit maximizing point occurs when \(Q=3\).

    At this point, the price of widgets is $13.50, the monopoly’s total revenue is $40.50, the total cost is $18, and profit is $22.50. For comparison, it is easy to see that if the firm produced two widgets price would be $14 and profit would be $20; if it produced four widgets price would be $13 and profit would again be $20. Q=3 must be the profit-maximizing output for the monopoly.

    Graphically, one can find a monopoly’s price, output, and profit by examining the demand, marginal cost, and marginal revenue curves. Again, the firm will always set output at a level at which marginal cost equals marginal revenue, so the quantity is found where these two curves intersect. Price, however, is determined by the demand for the good when that quantity is produced. Because a monopoly’s marginal revenue is always below the demand curve, the price will always be above the marginal cost at equilibrium, providing the firm with an economic profit.

    11.3: Monopoly Production and Pricing Decisions and Profit Outcome (7)

    Monopoly Pricing: Monopolies create prices that are higher, and output that is lower, than perfectly competitive firms. This causes economic inefficiency.

    Key Points

    • In a perfectly competitive market, there are many producers and consumers, no barriers to exit and entry into the market, perfectly hom*ogenous goods, perfect information, and well-defined property rights.
    • Perfectly competitive producers are price takers that can choose how much to produce, but not the price at which they can sell their output.
    • A monopoly exists when there is only one producer and many consumers.
    • Monopolies are characterized by a lack of economic competition to produce the good or service and a lack of viable substitute goods.
    • Firm typically have marginal costs that are low at low levels of production but that increase at higher levels of production.
    • While competitive firms experience marginal revenue that is equal to price – represented graphically by a horizontal line – monopolies have downward-sloping marginal revenue curves that are different than the good’s price.
    • For monopolies, marginal revenue is always less than price.
    • The first-order condition for maximizing profits in a monopoly is 0=∂q=p(q)+qp′(q)−c′(q), where q = the profit-maximizing quantity.
    • A monopoly’s profits are represented by π=p(q)q−c(q), where revenue = pq and cost = c.
    • Monopolies have the ability to limit output, thus charging a higher price than would be possible in competitive markets.
    • Unlike a competitive company, a monopoly can decrease production in order to charge a higher price.
    • Because of this, rather than finding the point where the marginal cost curve intersects a horizontal marginal revenue curve (which is equivalent to good’s price), we must find the point where the marginal cost curve intersect a downward-sloping marginal revenue curve.
    • Monopolies have downward sloping demand curves and downward sloping marginal revenue curves that have the same y-intercept as demand but which are twice as steep.
    • The shape of the curves shows that marginal revenue will always be below demand.
    • Typically a monopoly selects a higher price and lesser quantity of output than a price-taking company.
    • A monopoly, unlike a perfectly competitive firm, has the market all to itself and faces the downward-sloping market demand curve.
    • Graphically, one can find a monopoly’s price, output, and profit by examining the demand, marginal cost, and marginal revenue curves.

    Key Terms

    • perfect competition: A type of market with many consumers and producers, all of whom are price takers
    • network externality: The effect that one user of a good or service has on the value of that product to other people
    • perfect information: The assumption that all consumers know all things, about all products, at all times, and therefore always make the best decision regarding purchase.
    • marginal revenue: The additional profit that will be generated by increasing product sales by one unit.
    • marginal cost: The increase in cost that accompanies a unit increase in output; the partial derivative of the cost function with respect to output. Additional cost associated with producing one more unit of output.
    • first-order condition: A mathematical relationship that is necessary for a quantity to be maximized or minimized.
    • deadweight loss: A loss of economic efficiency that can occur when an equilibrium is not Pareto optimal.
    • economic profit: The difference between the total revenue received by the firm from its sales and the total opportunity costs of all the resources used by the firm.
    • demand: The desire to purchase goods and services.

    LICENSES AND ATTRIBUTIONS

    CC LICENSED CONTENT, SPECIFIC ATTRIBUTION

    • Monopoly. Provided by: Wikipedia. Located at: en.Wikipedia.org/wiki/Monopoly. License: CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
    • perfect information. Provided by: Wikipedia. Located at: en.Wikipedia.org/wiki/perfect%20information. License: CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
    • Boundless. Provided by: Boundless Learning. Located at: www.boundless.com//economics/...ct-competition. License: CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
    • network externality. Provided by: Wikipedia. Located at: en.Wikipedia.org/wiki/network%20externality. License: CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
    • Electricalgrid. Provided by: Wikipedia. Located at: en.Wikipedia.org/wiki/File:Electricalgrid.jpg. License: Public Domain: No Known Copyright
    • marginal cost. Provided by: Wiktionary. Located at: en.wiktionary.org/wiki/marginal_cost. License: CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
    • marginal revenue. Provided by: Wikipedia. Located at: en.Wikipedia.org/wiki/marginal%20revenue. License: CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
    • Monopoly. Provided by: Wikipedia. Located at: en.Wikipedia.org/wiki/Monopoly. License: CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
    • Electricalgrid. Provided by: Wikipedia. Located at: en.Wikipedia.org/wiki/File:Electricalgrid.jpg. License: Public Domain: No Known Copyright
    • Imperfect competition in the short run. Provided by: Wikimedia. Located at: commons.wikimedia.org/wiki/Fi..._short_run.svg. License: CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
    • Economics Perfect competition. Provided by: Wikimedia. Located at: commons.wikimedia.org/wiki/Fi...ompetition.svg. License: CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
    • Boundless. Provided by: Boundless Learning. Located at: www.boundless.com//economics/...rder-condition. License: CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
    • deadweight loss. Provided by: Wikipedia. Located at: en.Wikipedia.org/wiki/deadweight%20loss. License: CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
    • Electricalgrid. Provided by: Wikipedia. Located at: en.Wikipedia.org/wiki/File:Electricalgrid.jpg. License: Public Domain: No Known Copyright
    • Imperfect competition in the short run. Provided by: Wikimedia. Located at: commons.wikimedia.org/wiki/Fi..._short_run.svg. License: CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
    • Economics Perfect competition. Provided by: Wikimedia. Located at: commons.wikimedia.org/wiki/Fi...ompetition.svg. License: CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
    • Imperfect competition in the short run. Provided by: Wikimedia. Located at: commons.wikimedia.org/wiki/Fi..._short_run.svg. License: CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
    • marginal cost. Provided by: Wiktionary. Located at: en.wiktionary.org/wiki/marginal_cost. License: CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
    • Monopoly. Provided by: Wikipedia. Located at: en.Wikipedia.org/wiki/Monopoly. License: CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
    • marginal revenue. Provided by: Wikipedia. Located at: en.Wikipedia.org/wiki/marginal%20revenue. License: CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
    • Electricalgrid. Provided by: Wikipedia. Located at: en.Wikipedia.org/wiki/File:Electricalgrid.jpg. License: Public Domain: No Known Copyright
    • Imperfect competition in the short run. Provided by: Wikimedia. Located at: commons.wikimedia.org/wiki/Fi..._short_run.svg. License: CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
    • Economics Perfect competition. Provided by: Wikimedia. Located at: commons.wikimedia.org/wiki/Fi...ompetition.svg. License: CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
    • Imperfect competition in the short run. Provided by: Wikimedia. Located at: commons.wikimedia.org/wiki/Fi..._short_run.svg. License: CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
    • Imperfect competition in the short run. Provided by: Wikimedia. Located at: commons.wikimedia.org/wiki/Fi..._short_run.svg. License: CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
    • Monopoly. Provided by: Wikipedia. Located at: en.Wikipedia.org/wiki/Monopol...lasticity_rule. License: CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
    • Monopoly profit. Provided by: Wikipedia. Located at: en.Wikipedia.org/wiki/Monopoly_profit. License: CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
    • demand. Provided by: Wiktionary. Located at: en.wiktionary.org/wiki/demand. License: CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
    • Boundless. Provided by: Boundless Learning. Located at: www.boundless.com//economics/...omic-profit--2. License: CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
    • Electricalgrid. Provided by: Wikipedia. Located at: en.Wikipedia.org/wiki/File:Electricalgrid.jpg. License: Public Domain: No Known Copyright
    • Imperfect competition in the short run. Provided by: Wikimedia. Located at: commons.wikimedia.org/wiki/Fi..._short_run.svg. License: CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
    • Economics Perfect competition. Provided by: Wikimedia. Located at: commons.wikimedia.org/wiki/Fi...ompetition.svg. License: CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
    • Imperfect competition in the short run. Provided by: Wikimedia. Located at: commons.wikimedia.org/wiki/Fi..._short_run.svg. License: CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
    • Imperfect competition in the short run. Provided by: Wikimedia. Located at: commons.wikimedia.org/wiki/Fi..._short_run.svg. License: CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
    • Monopoly pricing example 01. Provided by: Wikimedia. Located at: commons.wikimedia.org/wiki/Fi...example_01.svg. License: CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
    11.3: Monopoly Production and Pricing Decisions and Profit Outcome (2024)

    FAQs

    How do monopolies make production and pricing decisions? ›

    Therefore, monopolies must make a decision about where to set their price and the quantity of their supply to maximize profits. They can either choose their price, or they can choose the quantity that they will produce and allow market demand to set the price.

    Which of the following is an outcome of a monopoly market? ›

    Since a monopoly is the only producer in a market they can set prices and it usually is higher than in a competitive market. The monopoly will try to artificially limit supply and thus increase prices to the point that maximizes profits.

    What are the 5 examples of monopoly? ›

    Table of contents
    • Monopoly Example #1 – Railways.
    • Monopoly Example #2 – Luxottica.
    • Monopoly Example #3 -Microsoft.
    • Monopoly Example #4 – AB InBev.
    • Monopoly Example #5 – Google.
    • Monopoly Example #6 – Patents.
    • Monopoly Example #7 – AT&T.
    • Monopoly Example #8 – Facebook.

    How do you calculate profit-maximizing output in monopoly? ›

    A monopolist wants to maximize profit, and profit = total revenue - total costs. So, d(TR)/dQ−d(TC)/dQ=0 is the same as d(TR)/dQ=d(TC)/dQ , which is the same as MR = MC.

    What is monopoly explain the price and output determination in it? ›

    Monopoly refers to a market structure in which there is a single producer or seller that has a control on the entire market. This single seller deals in the products that have no close substitutes and has a direct demand, supply, and prices of a product.

    What pricing strategy does monopoly use? ›

    Monopolistic Competitive Market Pricing Strategy

    In a monopolistic competitive market, companies set prices for their products. Since every company sells a product that might be the same as that of another company, each company can successfully set its prices.

    Which of the following statement is true in case of monopoly Mcq? ›

    Top Answer

    a . Explanation: Monopoly is a market condition where there is a single seller, who sells a unique commodity in the market. There is a barrier to exit and entry in the market.

    What is monopoly market Mcq? ›

    Monopoly is a market that has a few large firms. Duopoly is a market that has a few large firms. Perfect competition is a market that has a few large firms.

    What is the economic outcome of monopoly? ›

    Traditionally, monopolies benefit the companies that have them, as they can raise prices and reduce services without consequence. However, they can harm consumer interests because there is no suitable competition to encourage lower prices or better-quality offerings.

    What are the 3 factors of monopoly? ›

    Monopolies arise in the market due to the following three reasons.
    • The firm owns a key resource, for example, Debeers and Diamonds.
    • The firm receives exclusive rights by the government to produce a particular product. ...
    • One producer can be more efficient than others due to the cost of production.

    What is monopoly and its types? ›

    - May 22, 2021. A monopoly is an economic market structure where one company or one seller dominates with many buyers. There is a unique product in this market, and a seller enjoys the power of deciding the price of goods as he does not have competitors for that particular product.

    What is the formula for monopoly profit? ›

    The profit-maximizing choice for the monopoly will be to produce at the quantity where marginal revenue is equal to marginal cost: that is, MR = MC. If the monopoly produces a lower quantity, then MR > MC at those levels of output, and the firm can make higher profits by expanding output.

    How do you calculate monopoly profit? ›

    A monopolist calculates its profit or loss by using its average cost (AC) curve to determine its production costs and then subtracting that number from total revenue (TR). Recall from previous lectures that firms use their average cost (AC) to determine profitability.

    How do you find profit-maximizing price and output? ›

    The profit maximization formula depends on profit = Total revenue – Total cost. Therefore, a firm maximizes profit when MR = MC, which is the first order, and the second order depends on the first order. This concept differs from wealth maximization in terms of duration for earning profit and the firm's goals.

    How monopoly determined price and output in short run? ›

    Once the price falls below the average variable cost, monopolist will stop production. Thus, a monopolist in the short run equilibrium may bear the minimum loss, equal to fixed costs. Therefore, equilibrium price will be equal to average variable cost. This situation can also be explained with the help of Fig.

    How is price and output determined under monopoly competition? ›

    , In monopolistic competition, firms make price/output decisions as if they were a monopoly. In other words, they will produce where marginal revenue equals marginal cost. , Free entry into the market may ultimately shrink the economic profits of monopolistically competitive firms.

    How is price output and profit determined under monopoly in short and long run? ›

    The equilibrium price and output is determined at a point where the short-run marginal cost (SMC) equals marginal revenue (MR). Since costs differ in the short-run, a firm with lower unit costs will be earning only normal profits. In case, it is able to cover just the average variable cost, it incurs losses.

    What is the pricing power of monopoly? ›

    A monopoly can hike its prices usually because they do not have a direct competitor in the market. Monopolies, therefore, have strong pricing power. An example is a network company that supplies the internet all through the city.

    Is monopoly pricing is always high? ›

    Answer and Explanation: Monopoly does not always charge higher prices than perfect competition because of the issue of sustainability of a firm in long run. A monopolist can charge any price, but if it's too high, the consumer will reduce the consumption of that good.

    Which of the following is not a feature of monopoly market Mcq? ›

    Answer and Explanation: The correct answer is: c. free entry and exit. Free entry and exit are not characteristics of a monopoly.

    Which one of the following is not the feature of the monopoly market Mcq? ›

    Detailed Solution. Option 1 is NOT a feature of a Monopoly Market. In a monopoly market, the seller faces no competition, as he is the sole seller of goods with no close substitute.

    Which one of the following is the condition of equilibrium for the monopolist Mcq? ›

    The conditions for Equilibrium in Monopoly are the same as those under perfect competition. The marginal cost (MC) is equal to the marginal revenue (MR) and the MC curve cuts the MR curve from below.

    Why is it called monopoly? ›

    The game is named after the economic concept of a monopoly—the domination of a market by a single entity.

    What is called monopoly? ›

    Definition: A market structure characterized by a single seller, selling a unique product in the market. In a monopoly market, the seller faces no competition, as he is the sole seller of goods with no close substitute.

    What is monopoly simple? ›

    Monopoly is a situation where there is a single seller in the market. In conventional economic analysis, the monopoly case is taken as the polar opposite of perfect competition.

    Does a monopoly outcome result in an efficient outcome? ›

    A monopoly firm produces an output that is less than the efficient level. The result is a deadweight loss to society, given by the area between the demand and marginal cost curves over the range of output between the output chosen by the monopoly firm and the efficient output.

    What is the conclusion of monopoly? ›

    In monopolistic markets, the monopolist sets the price and that's it. There is no place for price discrimination at all. In a healthy competitive market, the price is set through different companies competing with each other.

    What are effects of monopoly? ›

    The disadvantages of monopolies include price-fixing, low-quality products, lack of incentive for innovation, and cost-push inflation.

    What is a monopoly example? ›

    Monopoly. A monopoly is a firm who is the sole seller of its product, and where there are no close substitutes. An unregulated monopoly has market power and can influence prices. Examples: Microsoft and Windows, DeBeers and diamonds, your local natural gas company.

    What are the bases of monopoly? ›

    The sources of monopoly power include economies of scale, locational advantages, high sunk costs associated with entry, restricted ownership of key inputs, and government restrictions, such as exclusive franchises, licensing and certification requirements, and patents.

    How do you solve a monopoly? ›

    Monopoly is always in an advantageous position to fix the price of a commodity in a way it likes another exploit the society.
    ...
    Some of important measures are:
    1. Anti Trust Legislation: ...
    2. Control over Prices: ...
    3. Organised Consumer's Associations: ...
    4. Effective Publicity: ...
    5. Creating Fair Competitions:

    What is characteristics of monopoly? ›

    Characteristics of a monopoly market

    Monopolies price goods as they want because they don't have any competition. Without competition to drop prices to attract customers, monopolies are free to charge any price, making them the price maker. This also means the monopoly business becomes the controller of the product.

    What products are monopoly? ›

    The U.S. markets that operate as monopolies or near-monopolies in the U.S. include providers of water, natural gas, telecommunications, and electricity.
    • Notably, these monopolies were actually created by government action. ...
    • Monopolies can be broken up by government action.

    How is monopoly power measured? ›

    Economists use the Lerner Index to measure monopoly power, also called market power. The index is the percent markup of price over marginal cost. The Lerner Index is a positive number (L >= 0), increasing in the amount of market power.

    What is monopoly theory? ›

    – Monopoly Theory of Profit posit that the firms enjoying the monopoly power restricts the output and charge higher prices for its products and services, than under perfect completion.

    What is monopoly in real life? ›

    Under monopoly, only one firm exists in a particular industry. There is one single seller who sells unique products with no substitutes and no competitors. The seller enjoys the power of setting of the prices according to his own wish. There are several examples of the monopoly according to the different situations.

    What are 4 characteristics of a monopoly? ›

    The following are the characteristics of a monopolistic market:
    • Single supplier. A monopolistic market is regulated by a single supplier. ...
    • Barriers to entry and exit. ...
    • Profit maximizer. ...
    • Unique product. ...
    • Price discrimination.

    What is the formula of profit? ›

    Finding profit is simple using this formula: Total Revenue - Total Expenses = Profit.

    What is the rule formula of profit? ›

    Profit arises when the selling price of any product sold is greater than the cost price (that is the price at which the product was originally bought).
    ...
    Formulas to Calculate Profit.
    Formula for ProfitProfit = S.P – C.P.
    Gross Profit FormulaGross Profit = Revenue – Cost of Goods Sold
    3 more rows
    15 Jul 2020

    What is meant by monopoly profit? ›

    third type of profit is monopoly profit, which occurs when a firm restricts output so as to prevent prices from falling to the level of costs. The first two types of profit result from relaxing the usual theoretical assumptions of unchanging consumer tastes and states of technology.

    What are the main factors that influence the profitability of monopoly? ›

    The factors that allow a firm to have monopoly profits are detailed below:
    • Economies of scale result in the downward-sloping portion of a firm's long-run average total cost curve (LRATC), permitting lower average costs to be achieved as the firm increases its size. ...
    • Branding. ...
    • Legal barriers.

    How do you find the maximum profit on a profit function? ›

    We know that to maximize profit, marginal revenue must equal marginal cost. This means we need to find C'(x) (marginal cost) and we need the Revenue function and its derivative, R'(x) (marginal revenue). To maximize profit, we need to set marginal revenue equal to the marginal cost, and solve for x.

    How do you calculate profit-maximizing price and quantity in perfect competition? ›

    The rule for a profit-maximizing perfectly competitive firm is to produce the level of output where Price= MR = MC, so the raspberry farmer will produce a quantity of 90, which is labeled as e in Figure 4 (a). Remember that the area of a rectangle is equal to its base multiplied by its height.

    How do monopolies influence prices in the market? ›

    In a monopoly, a single supplier controls the entire supply of a product. This creates a rigid demand curve. That is, demand for the product remains relatively stable no matter how high (or low) its price goes. Supply can be restricted to keep prices high.

    What is the role of the monopoly as a price maker? ›

    A monopolist is considered to be a price maker, and can set the price of the product that it sells. However, the monopolist is constrained by consumer willingness and ability to purchase the good, also called demand.

    How the pricing decisions are made? ›

    Pricing depends on various factors like manufacturing cost, raw material cost, profit margin etc. Pricing objective is to price the product such that maximum profit can be extracted from it. Pricing of a product is influenced by various factors as price involves many variables.

    What factors affect monopoly? ›

    Description: In a monopoly market, factors like government license, ownership of resources, copyright and patent and high starting cost make an entity a single seller of goods. All these factors restrict the entry of other sellers in the market.

    Is monopoly good for the economy? ›

    Monopolies are generally considered to be bad for consumers and the economy. When markets are dominated by a small number of big players, there's a danger that these players can abuse their power to increase prices to customers.

    How does monopoly affect the economy? ›

    Monopolies are able to make super profits by raising prices, limiting the supply of their products, restraining the growth of production capacity, inhibiting the introduction of new, cheaper products, directing technical research to the development of such products and technologies that not only do not reduce the cost, ...

    What is the main purpose of monopoly? ›

    Monopoly is a real-estate board game for two to eight players. The player's goal is to remain financially solvent while forcing opponents into bankruptcy by buying and developing pieces of property. Bankruptcy results in elimination from the game. The last player remaining on the board is the winner.

    Why pricing decision is most important factor in business decision? ›

    Pricing is considered part of a company's marketing strategy because it influences its relationship with customers: When prices are fair and competitive, customers come back, increasing the profitability of the business.

    What is the importance of pricing decision? ›

    Why is pricing important? In markets with increasing volume and price pressure, the right pricing approach is essential to remain competitive. It brings you the value you deserve for your products and services offered and secures the profits you need to invest in change and growth.

    What factors influence pricing decisions? ›

    Three important factors are whether the buyers perceive the product offers value, how many buyers there are, and how sensitive they are to changes in price. In addition to gathering data on the size of markets, companies must try to determine how price sensitive customers are.

    Top Articles
    Latest Posts
    Article information

    Author: Margart Wisoky

    Last Updated:

    Views: 6338

    Rating: 4.8 / 5 (58 voted)

    Reviews: 81% of readers found this page helpful

    Author information

    Name: Margart Wisoky

    Birthday: 1993-05-13

    Address: 2113 Abernathy Knoll, New Tamerafurt, CT 66893-2169

    Phone: +25815234346805

    Job: Central Developer

    Hobby: Machining, Pottery, Rafting, Cosplaying, Jogging, Taekwondo, Scouting

    Introduction: My name is Margart Wisoky, I am a gorgeous, shiny, successful, beautiful, adventurous, excited, pleasant person who loves writing and wants to share my knowledge and understanding with you.