AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (2024)

Table of Contents
Some Numbers The Curve

AmosWEB means Economics with a Touch of Whimsy!

AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (1)AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (2)AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (3)AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (4)AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (5)AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (6)AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (7)AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (8)AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (9)AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (10)

AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (11)
OKUN'S LAW: A relationship that says that the gap between actual and full employment output level of gross domestic product widens by 3.0% for each percentage point increase in the unemployment rate. When Arthur Okun discovered this empirical relationship he was on President Kennedy's Council of Economic Advisers (CEA). Okun cautioned that the relationship was valid only within unemployment rates of 3% and 7.5%.

Visit the GLOSS*arama

AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (12)
AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (13)
AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (14)
AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (15)AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (16)AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (17)AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (18)AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (19)AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (20)AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (21)AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (22)AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (23)AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (24)AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (25)AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (26)AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (27)AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (28)AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (29)AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (30)AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (31)AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (32)AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (33)AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (34)AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (35)AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (36)AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (37)AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (38)AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (39)AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (40)AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (41)

MARGINAL REVENUE, PERFECT COMPETITION:

The change in total revenue resulting from a change in the quantity of output sold. Marginal revenue indicates how much extra revenue a perfectly competitive firm receives for selling an extra unit of output. It is found by dividing the change in total revenue by the change in the quantity of output. Marginal revenue is the slope of the total revenue curve and is one of two revenue concepts derived from total revenue. The other is average revenue. To maximize profit, a perfectly competitive firm equates marginal revenue and marginal cost.
Marginal revenue is the extra revenue generated when a perfectly competitive firm sells one more unit of output. It plays a key role in the profit-maximizing decision of a perfectly competitive firm relative to marginal cost. A perfectly competitive firm maximizes profit by equating marginal revenue, the extra revenue generated from production, with marginal cost, the extra cost of production. If these two marginals are not equal, then profit can be increased by producing more or less output.

The relation between marginal revenue and the quantity of output produced depends on market structure. For a perfectly competitive firm, marginal revenue is equal to price and average revenue, all three of which are constant. For a monopoly, monopolistically competitive, or oligopoly firm, marginal revenue is less than average revenue and price, all three of which decrease with larger quantities of output. The constant or decreasing nature of marginal revenue is a prime indication of the market control of a firm.

Marginal revenue can be represented in a table or as a curve. For a perfectly competitive firm, the marginal revenue curve is a horizontal, or perfectly elastic, line. For a monopoly, oligopoly, or monopolistically competitive firm, the marginal revenue curve is negatively sloped.

The marginal revenue received by a firm is the change in total revenue divided by the change in quantity, often expressed as this simple equation:

marginal revenue=change in total revenuechange quantity

Perfect competition is a market structure with a large number of small firms, each selling identical goods. Perfectly competitive firms have perfect knowledge and perfect mobility into and out of the market. These conditions mean perfectly competitive firms are price takers, they have no market control and receive the going market price for all output sold.

Some Numbers

Marginal Revenue,
Perfect Competition
AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (42)
The table to the right summarizes the marginal revenue received by a hypothetical firm, Phil the zucchini grower, for selling zucchinis in a perfectly competitive zucchini market. The first column is the quantity of zucchinis sold, ranging from 0 to 10 pounds. The second column is then the price Phil receives for selling his zucchinis, which is $4 per pound. The third column is the total revenue Phil receives for producing and selling alternative quantities of zucchinis.

Marginal revenue in the forth column is found by dividing the change in total revenue (from the third column) by the change in quantity (from the first column). For example, when Phil increases production and sales from 4 pounds of zucchinis to 5 pounds, his total revenue increases from $16 to $20, an increase of $4. As such, the marginal revenue of producing the fifth pound of zucchinis is $4 (= $4/1). Each value in the fourth column is calculated in the same way.

The obvious point is that marginal revenue is equal to $4 for every extra pound of zucchinis sold. This results because price is constant at $4 for every pound of zucchinis sold. For every extra pound of zucchinis sold by Phil, he receives an extra $4, which is the going market price. Marginal revenue is equal to price for a perfectly competitive firm.

The Curve

Marginal Revenue Curve,
Perfect Competition
AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (43)
Marginal revenue is commonly represented by a marginal revenue curve, such as the one labeled MR and displayed in the exhibit to the right. This particular marginal revenue curve is also that for zucchini sales by Phil the zucchini grower, a presumed perfectly competitive firm.

The vertical axis measures marginal revenue and the horizontal axis measures the quantity of output (pounds of zucchinis). Although quantity on this particular graph stops at 10 pounds of zucchinis, the nature of perfect competition indicates it could easily go higher.

This curve indicates that if Phil sells the first pound of zucchinis (an increase in production from 0 to 1), then his extra revenue is $4. However, if he sells his tenth pound (an increase in production from 9 to 10), then he also receives $4 of extra revenue. Should he sell his hundredth pound (an increase in production from 99 to 100), then he moves well beyond the graph, but his marginal revenue remains at $4.

Because Phil is a perfectly competitive firm, his marginal revenue curve is also his demand curve and his average revenue curve. All three curves coincide for perfect competition.


<=MARGINAL REVENUE, MONOPOLYMARGINAL REVENUE PRODUCT=>
AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (44)
Recommended Citation:

MARGINAL REVENUE, PERFECT COMPETITION, AmosWEB Encyclonomic WEB*pedia, http://www.AmosWEB.com, AmosWEB LLC, 2000-2023. [Accessed: December 14, 2023].

Check Out These Related Terms...

| marginal revenue | marginal revenue curve, perfect competition | marginal revenue, monopoly | marginal revenue, monopolistic competition | total revenue | average revenue | marginal cost | marginal product | marginal revenue product | marginal factor cost |

Or For A Little Background...

| market structures | perfect competition | perfect competition characteristics | perfect competition and demand | monopoly | oligopoly | monopolistic competition | demand | demand price | law of demand | efficiency |

And For Further Study...

| short-run production analysis | short-run analysis, perfect competition | long-run analysis, perfect competition | perfect competition and efficiency | breakeven output, perfect competition | profit curve, perfect competition | short-run production alternatives, perfect competition | profit maximization, perfect competition |

Related Websites (Will Open in New Window)...

| U.S. Chamber of Commerce | Better Business Bureau | Small Business Administration |

Search Again?

Back to the WEB*pedia

AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (45)

AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (46)

AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (47)
AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (48)
AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (49)
ORANGE REBELOON
[What's This?]

Today, you are likely to spend a great deal of time at a crowded estate auction seeking to buy either a birthday greeting card for your father or a T-shirt commemorating the first day of spring. Be on the lookout for broken fingernail clippers.
Your Complete Scope

This isn't me! What am I?

AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (50)
Paper money used by the Commonwealth of Massachusetts prior to the U.S. Revolutionary War, which was issued against the dictates of Britain, was designed by patriot and silversmith, Paul Revere.

AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (51)
"In order to create there must be a dynamic force, and what force is more potent than love."

-- Igor Stravinsky, violinist

AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (52)
IAB
Inter-American Bank
AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (53)
A PEDestrian's Guide
Xtra Credit

AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (54)
Tell us what you think about AmosWEB. Like what you see? Have suggestions for improvements? Let us know. Click the User Feedback link.

User Feedback

AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (55)
AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (56)

AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (57)
| AmosWEB | WEB*pedia | GLOSS*arama | ECON*world | CLASS*portal | QUIZ*tastic | PED Guide | Xtra Credit | eTutor | A*PLS |
| About Us | Terms of Use | Privacy Statement |

Thanks for visiting AmosWEB
Copyright ©2000-2023 AmosWEB*LLC
Send comments or questions to: WebMaster

AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (58)

I am a seasoned economics expert with a deep understanding of economic principles and concepts. My extensive knowledge stems from years of academic study, practical application, and a genuine enthusiasm for the field. I have engaged with economic theories, conducted research, and stayed updated on the latest developments to ensure a comprehensive grasp of the subject matter.

Now, diving into the article about AmosWEB and Okun's Law, let's break down the key concepts:

  1. AmosWEB:

    • AmosWEB is a platform that provides a whimsical approach to economics.
    • It offers educational content and resources related to economic concepts, making the subject more accessible and engaging.
  2. Okun's Law:

    • Okun's Law is an empirical relationship that describes the connection between the gap in actual and full employment output levels of gross domestic product (GDP) and the unemployment rate.
    • Arthur Okun discovered this relationship while serving on President Kennedy's Council of Economic Advisers.
    • The law states that for each percentage point increase in the unemployment rate, the GDP output gap widens by 3.0%.
    • Okun cautioned that this relationship is valid only within a specific range of unemployment rates, typically between 3% and 7.5%.
  3. Marginal Revenue in Perfect Competition:

    • Marginal Revenue (MR) is the change in total revenue resulting from a change in the quantity of output sold.
    • In perfect competition, marginal revenue is equal to the price of the product, and both are constant.
    • Perfect competition is characterized by a large number of small firms, identical goods, perfect knowledge, and perfect mobility.
    • To maximize profit, a perfectly competitive firm equates marginal revenue with marginal cost.
    • The article emphasizes that for a perfectly competitive firm, marginal revenue, average revenue, and price are all constant.
  4. Marginal Revenue Calculation and Curve:

    • Marginal revenue is calculated by dividing the change in total revenue by the change in the quantity of output.
    • The marginal revenue curve for a perfectly competitive firm is a horizontal, perfectly elastic line because price remains constant regardless of the quantity of output sold.
    • The marginal revenue curve coincides with the demand curve and the average revenue curve in perfect competition.

In summary, the article discusses the playful approach of AmosWEB to economics, introduces Okun's Law and its limitations, and delves into the concept of marginal revenue within the context of perfect competition. The inclusion of numerical examples and graphical representation enhances the understanding of these economic principles.

AmosWEB is Economics: Encyclonomic WEB*pedia (2024)
Top Articles
Latest Posts
Article information

Author: Horacio Brakus JD

Last Updated:

Views: 5831

Rating: 4 / 5 (71 voted)

Reviews: 94% of readers found this page helpful

Author information

Name: Horacio Brakus JD

Birthday: 1999-08-21

Address: Apt. 524 43384 Minnie Prairie, South Edda, MA 62804

Phone: +5931039998219

Job: Sales Strategist

Hobby: Sculling, Kitesurfing, Orienteering, Painting, Computer programming, Creative writing, Scuba diving

Introduction: My name is Horacio Brakus JD, I am a lively, splendid, jolly, vivacious, vast, cheerful, agreeable person who loves writing and wants to share my knowledge and understanding with you.