Diminishing Marginal Productivity — Agricultural Law and Management (2024)

Diminishing marginal productivity recognizes that a business manager cannot change the quantity of all inputs at one time. Instead, altering the level of one or more inputs while holding the level of other inputs constant is the realistic means of adjusting productivity. However, adding an input while holding other inputs constant will not increase productivity indefinitely. The reality that output will decline as more of one input is added is referred to a diminishing marginal productivity. The challenge is to determine the level of input that will maximize profit, rather than maximize production.

.

A common business goal is to earn a profit. Often this goal is stated as wanting to maximize profit or to earn as much profit as possible with the available resources.

.

Management has been described as decision making. Among the many decisions that managers make are questions about producing a good or service to achieve the goal of earning a profit. The questions include "what product should I produce," "how should I produce this product," and "how much should I produce" to maximize profit.

Or more practically, the questions might be "Should I change the way I produce my product to increase profit? Should I use a different quantity of the input to increase profit? Should I use a different input? Should I use a different combination of inputs? Should I try to produce more or less of the product? Should I produce a slightly different product? Should I make a major change by producing an entirely different product, and the list of questions goes on. What is consistent among these questions is the objective of earning a profit or increasing profit, and the need to analyze the business operation.

The answer to these questions is unique for each business and the manager needs to make these decisions. No one can make these decisions for the manager. It is his or her responsibility to consider these important issues.

Even though the goal of increasing profit may be the primary criterion for these decisions, it may not be the only criteria. However for the purpose of this discussion, it is assumed that the manager will always strive to make the decision that maximizes profit.

The purpose of this series of web pages is to review economic concepts that can help managers analyze their business situations. The explanation will not answer the managers' questions nor will it provide the detailed data needed to analyze the business' alternatives. Instead, the explanation provides a conceptual framework with which managers can assess their own opportunities.

The economic concepts reviewed in these pages can be referred to as production theory, and addresses the three questions introduced above -- what product should I produce to maximize profit, how should I produce the product to maximize profit, and how much of the product should I produce to maximize profit. The majority of the discussion addresses the third question -- how much should I produce. The other two questions are briefly addressed thereafter.

Note that each of these questions is based on the premise that one of the manager's goal is to maximize profit.

Throughout this discussion, an underlying proposition is that diminishing marginal productivity is real. This bit of reality will be the foundation for all of this discussion. Diminishing marginal productivity is discussed more fully in a subsequent section on this page.

How much output or product should the business produce to maximize profit (factor-product)

The purpose of this series of web pages is to present a general overview of several economic concepts relating to the broad topic of production theory. The topics include

  • diminishing marginal productivity
  • the production function
  • stages of production
  • determining the profit maximizing quantity of variable input and profit maximizing level of production
  • determining demand for the variable input
  • defining and determining the cost of producing the product
  • determining supply of the product, and
  • minimizing loss if the business is unable to generate a profit

Embedded in these topics are secondary discussions about 1) short-run versus long-run, 2) fixed inputs and variable inputs, and 3) fixed costs and variable costs. The discussion often uses "advancing technology" as an example to illustrate the application of these economic concepts. A relationship between enterprise analysis and production response also is suggested.

Several assumptions form the foundation for this discussion. The first assumption (as already introduced) is that the manager wants to produce the quantity of output that will maximize profit. A second assumption is that the business can increase production or output by using more input, and that increased output means increased profit.

As the second assumption is discussed in subsequent sections, it will become clear that this assumption is NOT always true. There are times when using more input will increase production and increase profit, but there also are times when using more input will increase output but decrease profit. Furthermore, there are times when using more input decreases production and profit.

Increasing input will NOT always lead to increased profit. Accordingly, the manager will not want to maximize production, but instead will want to use the level of input that produces the level of output that achieves the goal of maximizing profit.

The manager's task is to determine the profit maximizing level of quantity or level of input. The manager's decision could be restated as "how much input should I use to maximize profit."

This web page introduces why the answer to the simple question of "how much should I produce" is complex. The page also introduces how a manager can decide how much input to use to maximize profit.

Although the stated goal for managers may be to maximize profit, some of the concepts addressed on these pages also can be illustrated with other examples. For example, there are many recipes for making a chocolate cake but the recipes differ and thus the resulting cakes may differ. Despite these differences, those of us who enjoy chocolate cake would likely find many of these cakes to be acceptable, that is, they are substitutable even though they are not identical.

A third assumption is that there is more than one way or one "recipe" for producing a product. Take the example of a chocolate cake but think about it from a slightly different perspective. Instead of asking "how much input should I use to maximize profit," a baker may ask " how much chocolate should I use in making the cake?" That is, the baker could bake several cakes using the same amount of flour, sugar and milk and the same number of eggs, but vary the amount of chocolate in each cake. The cake made with a small quantity of chocolate may not have much flavor and thus not achieve the goal of baking a good chocolate cake. At the other extreme if the baker uses a large quantity of chocolate in one cake, the flavor may be bitter. Neither of these decisions achieve the goal of baking a good chocolate cake. Some quantity of chocolate between these two extremes will likely result in an acceptable cake.

A similar situation can arise for a wheat farmer who uses a small quantity of fertilizer per acre; the farmer may not reach the yield potential for the acre of land. However, using a large quantity of fertilizer may diminish production; that is, too much fertilizer can stunt the growth of the crop. Somewhere between these two extremes is the quantity of fertilizer that achieves the farmer's goal of maximizing profit from raising wheat on the acre of land.

There is more than one way to produce a product and the "recipe" that one business uses will be different than the recipe used by another business. Each manager must determine the "recipe" the works best for his or her business. What one manager does may not make sense for another manager. Each manager needs the skills to decide which "recipe" is most appropriate for his or her business.

In summary, the purpose of these materials is to introduce principles, including economic principles that help describe a decision making process for the baker, the farmer and many other managers. Restated, this series of web pages demonstrates that these economic concepts are relevant in making numerous production decisions.

  • The discussion initially assumes the managers (the decision makers) know what product (good or service) they want to produce.
  • The discussion recognizes that there are different ways to produce similar products.
  • The discussion also initially assumes that the managers know how to produce the product; that is, the managers have a general understanding of how they want to produce the product. Restated, the manager has determined what technology will be used to produce the product and what inputs will be used in the production process.
  • The discussion assumes a goal for the manager is to earn a profit from producing and selling the product. This goal is often stated as maximizing profit, but maximizing profit may not always be the managers' only goal.
  • Adding inputs is expected to increase production and profit, but in reality, adding inputs can decrease profit and in some situations, decrease production.
  • The purpose for these materials is to help decision makers understand how to analyze their business in order to make decisions that will advance the goal of earning a profit.

The next section introduces the concept of diminishing marginal productivity -- a natural phenomenon that impacts decision making.

.

Diminishing Marginal Productivity

This page introduces the economic concepts of 1) diminishing marginal productivity, 2) short-run and long-run, 3) fixed and variable inputs and 4) fixed and variable costs.

Diminishing marginal productivity is the understanding that using additional inputs will generally increase output, but there also is a point where adding more input will result in a smaller increase in the output, and there is another point where using even more input will lead to a decrease in output.

A hypothetical example:

  • Using no fertilizer to produce wheat may yield 15 bushels per acre.
  • Using 50 pounds of fertilizer may increase the yield to 25 bushels; that is, an increase of 10 bushels as a result of using 50 pounds of fertilizer.
  • Using another 50 pounds (for a total of 100 pounds) may increase the yield to 32 bushels; that is, the second 50 pounds of fertilizer increased the yield by only 7 bushels.
  • Furthermore, adding another 50 pounds (for a total of 150 pounds) may result in a yield of only 30 bushels; that is, the final 50 pounds of fertilizer actually damaged the crop and reduced the yield by 2 bushels.

We could develop a similar example using student study time; some study time will result in an improved understanding of the subject matter, but there will be a point where additional study time (e.g., repeatedly reviewing the same material) will not enhance the student's understanding. (However, this does NOT mean that students can get by investing NO time in studying!!)

A third example to illustrate diminishing marginal productivity could involve determining how many people should be assigned to the crew of a piano moving truck. One truck and one worker may not be an effective piano moving business because it is difficult for one person to move a piano. One truck with two or three workers might be quite productive. One truck with four, five or six workers may be less productive than if there were fewer workers. With too many workers, they begin to trip over one another, there is not enough room for all of them to lift on the piano at one time (so some workers merely watch the others move the piano), and there may not be enough room in the truck for all of them to travel from site to site.

We also can return to our previous example of a chocolate cake; adding more chocolate to the batter initially improves the taste of the cake, but adding even more chocolate will eventually detract from the taste of the cake.

As stated by others, if diminishing marginal productivity was not a reality, we could raise all the food we need in a flower pot by simply adding more seed, fertilizer, water, etc.

An almost endless list of examples could be developed to illustrate diminishing marginal productivity.

Diminishing marginal productivity is a natural phenomenon that economists recognize and incorporate into their thinking and analysis.

The following sections explain the impact of diminishing marginal productivity. The impacts of the concept are illustrated with the production function and cost curves. The discussion also considers how the concept of diminishing marginal productivity influences decision making. Finally, the relationship between these concepts and enterprise budget/analysis is introduced.

Assumptions

  • Business people want to make decisions that increase profit so the additional profit can be used by the business owners for personal needs and desires, such as food, housing, clothing, health care, education, and recreation. This assumption is usually stated as “a manager strives to maximize the business’ profit.”
  • One strategy to increase profit is to produce and sell more product in a given period of time (e.g., monthly, quarterly annually); this strategy is often based on the assumption that increased production by this one firm will not decrease the market price for the product.
  • Increased production requires additional input (we cannot produce something from nothing).
    • This assumption is revisited in a subsequent section that discusses the impact of advancing technology.
  • Often when a manager decides to use more input to produce more output, there is not an opportunity (there is not enough time) to increase all inputs; that is, some inputs (perhaps a building) are unchanged even though a larger quantity of other inputs are being used to increase output (such as, more flour is being made into dough and baked into bread inside the building). One of the preceding hypothetical examples held the land (one acre) constant as the amount of fertilizer was increased from 0 to 150 pounds. Another example held the number of trucks constant while changing the number of workers.
    • Each of these examples assumes that at least one input cannot be changed (the building, the land, the truck) while another input can be altered (the quantity of flour, fertilizer, or workers).

Short-run and Long-run

An assumption is that the manager wants to increase profit as quickly as possible, but this also implies there will not be enough time to increase ALL inputs, so the business will increase only SOME inputs. Restated, assuming that the manager wants to increase profit as soon as possible, there is not enough time to change the level of all inputs.

Not being able to change some inputs is defined as the short-run -- not enough time to change all inputs. The manager will try to change the level of production by changing only the level of variable inputs. Restated, there will be both fixed inputs and variable inputs. A fixed input is any input that cannot be changed in the time period the manager is contemplating.

Diminishing marginal productivity is the concept that using increasing amount of some inputs (variable inputs) during the production period while holding other inputs constant (fixed inputs) will eventually lead to decreasing productivity. Diminishing marginal productivity is a natural phenomenon that humans cannot avoid or eliminate.

The inability to change the level or quantity of at least one input due to the shortness of time is designated in economic theory as the short run. The long run, by comparison, means the business manager is contemplating a period of time that is long enough to alter or change all of the business assets.

Example. Buying additional flour or hiring another worker for a bakery usually can be accomplished in a relatively short time whereas constructing an addition to a building or buying another truck generally takes longer. If the business manager is contemplating a time frame in which additional flour can be purchased but the building cannot be expanded, economic theory would call that the short run because there is not enough time to change all the assets the business is using. If the business manager, however, is considering a time period long enough to change all the business assets, including an expansion of a building, for example, economic theory would describe that as the long run.

Many management decisions are made with the manager contemplating the short run; that is, enough time to change some inputs but not all inputs. The implication of thinking about the short-run is addressed again in a subsequent section.

  • Long-run is a period time long enough for the manager to alter the level or quantity of all inputs being used in the production process.
  • Short-run is a period of time that allows the manager to alter the level of some inputs but there is not enough time to alter the level of other inputs.

Assume the Short-run

Managerial decisions are often made under circ*mstances where the manager cannot alter all inputs being used in the production process. Instead, the manager can make some changes but has to rely on and use other resources as they currently exist; there just is not enough time to change everything. This is referred to as the “short-run.”

The concept of diminishing marginal productivity assumes the manager is making decisions to maximize profit in the short run.

The discussion on these pages assumes the short-run; that is, the manager wants to increase profit as quickly as possible. There is not enough time to increase all inputs; the business will try to increase output by increasing only some inputs.

Fixed inputs and Variable Inputs

The short-run introduces another economic concept -- fixed inputs and variable inputs. As already stated, in the short-run the quantity of some inputs can be changed but the quantity of other inputs cannot be altered. Economic theory refers to the inputs that can be changed as variable inputs and the inputs that cannot be altered in this time period as fixed inputs.

    • Variable inputs are the production inputs that can be altered in the short-run, for example, the business manager can easily use a greater quantity or a lesser quantity of the input during this production period.
    • Fixed inputs are the production inputs that cannot be altered in the short-run; even if the manager wants to use more or less of the input, there is not enough time to change the quantity of the input during this production period.

Fixed input v. long-term asset -- they are not the same.

Fixed inputs are those that cannot be easily altered. For example, land leased on a 3-month basis may be a variable input rather than a fixed input, but land that is leased on a 7-year contract may be relatively fixed. In the first case, the manager could discontinue leasing the land within 3 months whereas as the second manager is "stuck" with the land for as long as seven years even if the manager no longer wants to use the land.

Owned land may be more of a variable input than leased land. It may be easier to sell a tract of land if it is no longer needed than it may be to get out of a long-term lease agreement. Even though owned land is often used as an example of fixed input, it may not be a fixed asset if there are opportunities to sell it in a short time.

A piece of equipment that can be readily sold may be a variable input whereas a piece of specialized equipment that no one else is interested in buying would be a fixed input.

Some labor or workers might be a variable input -- hourly workers who can be told to "stay home today" because there is no work for them. Other workers, however, may be a fixed input such as those who are hired under a several-year contract that need to be paid even if there is no work for them.

Consider a family business. Is the labor provided by family members a variable input or a fixed input? How easy is it to "discharge" a family member if their labor is no longer needed in the family business?

Bottom line -- a fixed input is one that is not easily acquired or disposed of whereas inputs that can be easily bought and sold (even though they have a long useful life) may be viewed as a variable input. Do not confuse the economic definition of a fixed input with an asset that has a long useful life.

Fixed input becomes a variable input.

Fixed inputs become variable inputs as 1) the manager extends the time period being considered in the decision making process and 2) as the input reaches the point that it needs to be replaced. For example, a item of specialized equipment (as suggested above) is a fixed input if there is limited opportunity to sell the item. However, as the item grows old and reaches the end of its useful life, the manager now has an opportunity to decide whether to replace it or simply quit using it. At this point, this specialized equipment may shift (in the manager's mind) from being a fixed input to being a variable input.

The description of fixed inputs are addressed again in subsequent sections.

Variable and Fixed Costs

The issue of "fixed" versus "variable" cost is addressed in more detail in subsequent sections, but recognize for now that the costs of fixed inputs are considered “fixed costs” and the costs of variable inputs are considered “variable costs.”

Examples of cost associated with a fixed input include depreciation, maintenance, interest on debt associated with the asset, and opportunity cost of equity invested in the asset.

An important characteristic of a fixed input is that even if a fixed input is not being used, its cost is still being incurred. For example when a business decides to cease operation, the manager can eliminate the variable cost by not using any of the variable input (perhaps electricity), but the cost associated with the fixed inputs (which cannot be immediately disposed of) will continue to be incurred by the business (e.g., rent on a long-term lease that cannot be terminated) even if the business is not producing any product (revenue).

Applying the Concept of Diminishing Marginal Productivity in the Short-run

The concept of diminishing marginal productivity is apparent as managers make decisions in the short-run; that is, "how much variable input should I combine with my fixed inputs to achieve my goal of maximizing profit during this production period."

  • Diminishing marginal productivity describes the concept that productivity will decline if a manager tries to expand production by using a larger quantity of some (variable) inputs while using the same quantity of other (fixed) inputs during a time period.

In summary --

  • It is generally assumed that the level of output is directly related to the level of input, but our understanding (as summarized in economic theory) goes beyond that.
  • The inability to alter the productive capacity of an input (e.g., adopt new technology) or the length of time needed to vary the quantity of an input forces firms to use different proportions of inputs; that is, to increase output in the short run, the manager uses more of some inputs even though there is no opportunity to increase the quantity of all inputs.

    In the short run, there is not enough time to change the quantity of all inputs. The inputs that can be changed are referred to as variable input and their costs are variable costs. By comparison, inputs that cannot be changed are referred to as fixed inputs and result in fixed costs.

    In the long-run, all inputs can be altered; restated, all inputs and all costs are variable in the long-run.

  • The manager's timeframe is important. If there is not enough time to alter the level of use of all inputs, some inputs (fixed inputs) will remain unchanged even though other inputs (variable inputs) are being used in greater quantity in an effort to increase output.

    A THOUGHT: By identifying fixed and variable inputs, the manager knows which inputs can be changed during the production period.

  • Diminishing marginal productivity: if more units of a variable input are used in combination with fixed inputs, the rate of increase in total output will eventually decrease.

    A manager cannot add increasing amounts of variable input to fixed inputs during a production period without eventually decreasing output.

    As suggested in a “principles of economics” text (and as stated previously), we could raise all the food needed to feed the world in a flowerpot if diminishing marginal productivity was not real.

  • The inability to immediately alter the quantity of some inputs (e.g., fixed inputs) and the resulting reality of diminishing marginal productivity complicate managerial questions such as "should I change how much I produce," "should I change how I produce," and "should I change what I produce."

The next section illustrates an application of the concept of diminishing marginal productivity with a description of the production function.

Diminishing Marginal Productivity — Agricultural Law and Management (2024)

FAQs

Diminishing Marginal Productivity — Agricultural Law and Management? ›

The law of diminishing marginal productivity states that when an advantage is gained in a factor of production, the productivity gained from each subsequent unit produced will only increase marginally from one unit to the next.

What is the law of diminishing margin productivity? ›

An economic rule governing production which holds that if more variable input units are used along with a certain amount of fixed inputs, the overall output might grow at a faster rate initially, then at a steady rate, but ultimately, it will grow at a declining rate.

What is diminishing marginal returns in agriculture? ›

The law of diminishing marginal returns states that adding an additional factor of production results in smaller increases in output. After some optimal level of capacity utilization, the addition of any larger amounts of a factor of production will inevitably yield decreased per-unit incremental returns.

What is law of diminishing returns to scale in agriculture? ›

The law of Diminishing Returns states that in a production process with which all other factors are fixed except one if the quantity of the variable factor increases by a fixed rate, the level of production will increase by a decreasing rate.

What is the law of diminishing marginal consumption? ›

The law of diminishing marginal utility states that all else equal, as consumption increases, the marginal utility derived from each additional unit declines. Marginal utility is the incremental increase in utility that results from the consumption of one additional unit.

What are exceptions of diminishing marginal productivity? ›

Following are the Exceptions to the law of diminishing marginal utility: 1) Hobbies: In certain hobbies like the collection of various stamps and coins, rare paintings, music, reading, etc., the law does not hold true because every additional increase in the stock gives more pleasure. This increases marginal utility.

Why does the law of diminishing marginal productivity hold in the short run? ›

Diminishing returns to labour in the short run

This occurs only in the short run when at least one factor of production is fixed (e.g. capital) and so increasing a variable factor (e.g. labour) will result in the extra workers getting in each other's way, reducing productivity.

What is an example of the law of diminishing returns to scale? ›

A decreasing returns to scale occurs when the proportion of output is less than the desired increased input during the production process. For example, if input is increased by 3 times, but output is reduced 2 times, the firm or economy has experienced decreasing returns to scale.

What are the limitations of the law of diminishing returns? ›

The following are the limitations of the law of diminishing returns: This law, although considered to be useful in production activities, cannot be applied universally in all production scenarios. It becomes a constraint in cases where products are less natural. This law is most significant in agricultural production.

What is law of diminishing returns in soil fertility? ›

The law of diminishing returns states that there will be a. point where the additional output of corn gained from one. additional unit of fertilizer will be smaller than the additional. output of corn from the previous increase in fertilizer.

What are the stages of diminishing productivity? ›

Therefore we can say that there are three stages of the law of diminishing returns: Increase of marginal returns. Maximum marginal returns. Diminishing marginal returns.

What is the marginal productivity of the factors of production? ›

Marginal productivity refers to the additional output that results from an increase in input factors. The marginal productivity theory suggests that the amount paid to each factor in the production process is equal to the value of the extra output the factor of production produces.

How do you show diminishing marginal product? ›

Notice that the total product increases as more workers are added, but at a decreasing rate. The average product decreases as more workers are added, because the output per worker falls. The marginal product also decreases as more workers are added, because each additional worker adds less output than the previous one.

What is the marginal productivity theory? ›

Marginal productivity theory holds that the payment for any factor of production tends to be about equal to the value of its marginal product, where, in a multiproduct firm, the product used in the calculation is the one for which the value of marginal product is greatest.

What does the law of diminishing marginal productivity state quizlet? ›

The law of diminishing marginal productivity states that as more units of a variable input are added, holding other inputs constant (ceteris paribus), the additional output obtained from each new unit of the variable input eventually falls.

What is the formula for diminishing marginal product? ›

MP= ΔTP/ ΔL. This formula is important to relate back to diminishing rates of return. It finds the change in total product divided by change in labour. The Marginal Product formula suggests that MP should increase in the short run with increased labour.

Top Articles
Latest Posts
Article information

Author: Edwin Metz

Last Updated:

Views: 5978

Rating: 4.8 / 5 (78 voted)

Reviews: 93% of readers found this page helpful

Author information

Name: Edwin Metz

Birthday: 1997-04-16

Address: 51593 Leanne Light, Kuphalmouth, DE 50012-5183

Phone: +639107620957

Job: Corporate Banking Technician

Hobby: Reading, scrapbook, role-playing games, Fishing, Fishing, Scuba diving, Beekeeping

Introduction: My name is Edwin Metz, I am a fair, energetic, helpful, brave, outstanding, nice, helpful person who loves writing and wants to share my knowledge and understanding with you.