The rural non-farm sector: issues and evidence from developing countries (2024)

ScienceDirect

RegisterSign in

ViewPDF

  • Access throughyour institution

Article preview

  • Abstract
  • Introduction
  • Section snippets
  • References (94)
  • Cited by (276)
  • Recommended articles (6)

Agricultural Economics

Volume 26, Issue 1,

October 2001

, Pages 1-23

Author links open overlay panel

Abstract

The rural non-farm sector has traditionally been viewed as a low-productivity sector which produces low quality goods. It is often expected to wither away as a country develops. Recent years have seen a shift away from this position towards recognition that the rural non-farm sector can, and often does, contribute to economic growth, rural employment, poverty reduction, and a more spatially balanced population distribution. This paper reviews the literature on the conceptual and empirical underpinnings of this more recent perspective, focussing on the experience in developing countries. The paper documents the size and heterogeneity of the sector, pointing to evidence that in many countries the sector is expanding rather than declining. The issues associated with measuring the sector’s economic contribution are discussed, followed by empirical assessments for several countries and regions. The distributional impact of non-farm earnings is examined and it is found that a pro-poor impact, while by no means inevitable, can be considerable. The sector’s trajectory over time, in different settings, is reviewed and the scope for, and experience of, various policy interventions is discussed.

Introduction

The rural non-farm sector is a poorly understood component of the rural economy of developing countries and we know relatively little about its role in the broader development process. This gap in our knowledge is the product of the sector’s great heterogeneity, coupled with inadequate attention at both the empirical and theoretical level. A common view is that rural off-farm employment is a low productivity sector producing low quality goods, expected to wither away as a country develops and incomes rise. A corollary of this perspective is that government need not devote resources to promoting the sector, nor be concerned about negative repercussions on the rural non-farm sector arising from government policies directed at other objectives.

To some extent, opinion has been swinging away from this position. Arguments for paying attention to the non-farm sector generally center around the sector’s perceived potential in absorbing a growing rural labor force, in slowing rural–urban migration, in contributing to national income growth, and in promoting a more equitable distribution of income.

In most developing countries the bulk of the population lives in rural areas, and this population continues to grow at a substantial rate. Given limits to arable land, this growth in the rural labor force will not be productively absorbed in the agricultural sector. Either migration to urban areas or the development of non-farm employment in rural areas must take up the slack.

Most countries have seen a rapid increase in the level of urbanization. Over the period 1960–1980, rural out-migration and urban in-migration have been estimated at 1 and 1.8% annually for 40 developing countries with available data (Williamson, 1988). For some countries the rates have been much higher. For example, during the 1970s, Nigeria and Tanzania are estimated to have had 7.0 and 7.5% increases in urban population annually with over 60% due to rural–urban migration (Todaro, 1994).

Enterprises tend to congregate in urbanized areas in most countries, and to be large in scale, suggesting that there are substantial economies of scale, scope or agglomeration. A large local market, a locally available skilled workforce, a wider variety of production inputs, technological spillovers and lower costs to the provision of infrastructure are a few examples of the latter and they are real (social) benefits of concentration.

There are, however, reasons for industry to thrive in urbanized environments which do not reflect benefits to society. Some of these are created by governments. Requiring firms to obtain licenses for production or foreign exchange makes it advantageous for them to locate near government offices. The provision of high quality physical and social infrastructure in urban areas to an extent not warranted on the basis of lower costs is a phenomenon commonly observed in developing countries (and often ascribed to the presence of a political elite in cities). This lowers the relative costs of urban-based production in a way which is socially costly.

Perhaps most important, however, in causing a divergence between private decision-making and social benefits is the fact that firms do not incorporate most of the negative externalities, such as congestion, pollution and higher land values, that they impose when they decide to locate in a city. Most governments have voiced concern about this increasing concentration in UN surveys and many have expressed an interest in promoting economic activity in rural areas to encourage the population to stay in the countryside. This concern is shared by donor agencies and particularly non-governmental organizations (NGOs) who have become active in programs of credit, training and technical assistance to both rural and urban small-scale enterprises (see Meyer, 1992, Meyer, 1998 and Section 5).1

In addition to the problems of urbanization, it has been argued that rural enterprises are more productive, when appropriately measured, than are urban firms. Just as private location decisions need not be optimal from the perspective of society as a whole, production technology choices at the level of the firm can also be governed by incentives at odds with social priorities. It is often pointed out that for a number of reasons, often artifacts of government policies, relative factor costs diverge between rural and urban areas. The factor costs faced by rural-based enterprises are thought to more accurately reflect the social opportunity costs of those factors and hence the labor-intensive technologies used in rural locations are more socially “appropriate”. That is, they are more productive when inputs are measured in terms of their real, social, costs. Even if such activities do not generate very high labor income, in an environment with seasonal or permanent underemployment, any utilization of labor can contribute to raising total income. The oft-cited example of China’s labor-intensive township and village enterprises (TVEs) as the “engine of growth” behind that country’s remarkable growth performance during the past decades, suggests that even at conventional market prices the potential contribution of the sector to overall economic performance should not be underestimated.

Finally, there are distributional reasons to be interested in the non-farm rural sector (given that redistribution via taxes and transfers is politically and administratively costly in all countries). First, to the extent that rural industry produces lower quality goods which are more heavily consumed by the poor, good health of this sector has indirect distributional benefits via lowering prices to the poor. Second, it can provide a source of employment to the poor who, because they are small landholders or are landless, cannot find sustenance in agriculture. Third, through diversification it also supplies a way of smoothing income over years and seasons to people who have limited access to other risk coping mechanisms such as savings/credit or insurance. Fourth, growth in the non-farm sector can tighten agricultural labor markets, raising wages and/or reducing underemployment. As rural poverty in many countries is concentrated among landless agricultural laborers this tightening of labor markets can have a pronounced impact on poverty levels.2

Evidence concerning the productivity and distributional characteristics of the sector is examined in turn in 2 Characteristics of the non-farm sector — productivity, 3 Characteristics of the non-farm employment sector — inequality and poverty alleviation. Section 4 considers the dynamic potential of the sector, and in conclusion, Section 5 examines the role for policy. But first we look at some aggregate statistics which demonstrate that, while perhaps not the center of attention, the rural non-farm sector is large, and even growing, in most developing countries.

The non-farm “sector” includes all economic activities in rural areas except agriculture, livestock, fishing and hunting. Since it is defined negatively, as non-agriculture, it is not in any sense a hom*ogeneous sector. Judgements about the viability and importance of the rural non-farm sector hinge crucially on what is meant by “rural”. We will illustrate in this paper, e.g., non-farm activity undertaken by farm households as independent producers in their homes, the subcontracting of work to farm families by urban-based firms, non-farm activity in village and rural town enterprises, and commuting between rural residences and urban non-farm jobs. For example, Basant (1994) finds, in a survey of rural employment in the Indian State of Gujarat, that 25% of rural male non-agricultural workers commuted to urban areas for work.

Many different definitions of rural are used in the collection of census and survey information, making comparisons across countries difficult. Typically the distinction between rural and urban employment is based on the place of residence of workers, so those who commute to a job in a nearby urban center are considered to be rural workers. Rural is most often defined to include settlements of about 5000 or fewer inhabitants. However, the definitions of a rural locality, based on population size and/or functions and characteristics of the settlement such as whether it has a school or hospital, or happens to be the seat of local government, do vary. For example, in Table 1, which displays aggregate statistics for a number of countries based on their own definitions of rural, the definitions range from Mali and Zimbabwe, which designate as rural only settlements with less than 3000 and 2500 inhabitants, respectively, to Mauritania, which includes settlements with under 10000, to Taiwan, which excludes only cities over 250000 and two suburban counties surrounding Taipei (for further definitions, see Haggblade et al., 1989). Clearly, a more limited definition of rural lowers the percentage of employment which is found outside of agriculture.3

A number of features of the data suggest that the percentage of rural employment found in the non-farm sector may be underestimated for all countries. The figures in Table 1 refer in most cases only to primary employment. As will be discussed below in Section 3, one of the important roles of non-farm activities is to provide work in the slack periods of the agricultural cycle. Thus primary employment status will be an underestimate of the actual percentage of labor hours which are devoted to non-farm activities. After surveying farm management surveys and time allocation studies of African farm households, Haggblade et al. (1989) conclude that 15–65% of farmers have secondary employment in the non-farm sector and 15–40% of total family labor hours are devoted to income-generating non-farm activities. Note that this is income-generating activities. Much of non-farm activity in all developing countries, especially that of women, is unremunerated work, such as clothing production, food processing and education for the household, which is not included in employment figures. As countries develop, more of these tasks are commercialized and more non-farm employment appears in the statistics (although the problem never disappears, see Thomas, 1992). This is a second reason to expect an underestimate of non-farm activity. Finally, since rural enterprises are typically small and dispersed there is reason to think that they may simply be missed in surveys. (Anderson and Leierson, 1980, note that in some African countries under-remuneration has been as high as 40%.)

Bearing these considerations in mind, it is clear from Table 1 that the non-farm sector is substantial in many countries — both in terms of income and employment — and has, in the aggregate, been growing over time. For example, in China non-agricultural employment grew from 11% of total rural employment in 1980 to 20% by 1986.4 As indicated in Table 1, the non-farm sector is composed of services, commerce and transport, construction and mining, and manufacturing. There is some evidence to suggest that there is a shift in composition towards services and away from manufacturing in the smallest localities as development proceeds (see below).

Section snippets

Measures of productivity — theory

An important question when considering the potential contribution of non-farm activity to development is whether such activity is efficient in converting resources into output relative to its urban counterpart or agriculture. In studies of productivity three measures are commonly used. The first two are partial measures: labor productivity, which measures the value added by an activity (gross output deducting intermediate inputs, but not deducting capital and labor costs) per unit of labor

Characteristics of the non-farm employment sector — inequality and poverty alleviation

As described in the previous section, some activities in the non-farm sector provide workers with low returns even relative to casual agricultural wage labor. This is particularly true for non-farm labor performed by women. Such employment may nevertheless be very important from a welfare perspective for the following reasons: off-farm employment income may serve to reduce aggregate income inequality; where there exists seasonal or longer-term unemployment in agriculture households may benefit

Dynamic potential

In the 1960s, Hymer and Resnick (1969) formulated a model to explain the purported decline of rural non-farm activities under colonialism. They envisaged an initially self-sufficient economy producing both agricultural goods and other goods and services, labeled Z-goods, for local consumption. With the advent of colonial links there would arrive, on one hand, new opportunities for exporting cash crops and natural resources, and on the other, cheap and higher quality manufactured goods available

Policy implications: lessons and experience

This section considers what, if any, role there might be for government intervention in the non-farm sector. Governmental efforts to support the development of small-scale enterprises and specifically rural enterprises have traditionally taken the form of project assistance which is directed at targeted groups. These efforts have a fairly long history. Financial support programs were launched in Mexico, Venezuela and Argentina in the 1950s, and in Brazil, Chile and Colombia in the 1960s. These

Acknowledgements

An earlier version of this paper was prepared as a background paper for the World Bank’s 1995 World Development Report, Workers in an Integrated World (Lanjouw and Lanjouw, 1995). The authors thank the editor and two referees for helpful suggestions, and are also grateful for detailed comments from Gus Ranis and Dominique van de Walle. They also thank Harold Alderman, Robin Burgess, Emmanuel Jimenez, Jesko Hentschel, Alain de Janvry, Ashok Kotwal, Ramon Lopez, Keijiro Otsuka, Jean-Phillipe

References (94)

  • G. Ranis et al.Rural non-agricultural activities in development: theory and application

    J. Dev. Econ.

    (1993)

  • B. Lewis et al.District-level economic linkages in Kenya: evidence based on a small regional social accounting matrix

    World Dev.

    (1992)

  • S. Haggblade et al.Farm–nonfarm linkages in rural subSaharan Africa

    World Dev.

    (1989)

  • Adams, D., 1988. The conundrum of successful credit projects in floundering rural financial markets, Econ. Dev. Cult....
  • Adams, R., 1999. Nonfarm Income, Inequality and Land in Rural Egypt. Mimeo, PRMPO/MNSED, The World...
  • Ahmad, Q.K., 1990. Appropriate technology and rural industrial development in Bangladesh: the macro-context. In:...
  • Alexander, P., Boomgaard, P., White, B. (Eds.), 1991. In the Shadow of Agriculture: Non-farm Activities in the Javanese...
  • D. Anderson et al.

    Rural non-farm employment in developing countries

    Econ. Dev. Cult. Change

    (1980)

  • Aoki, M., Mudock, K., Oduno-Fujiwara, M., 1995. Beyond the East Asian miracle: introducing the market-enhancing view....
  • Bagachwa, M.D., Stewart, F., 1992. Rural industries and rural linkages. In: Stewart, F., Lall, S., Wangwe, S. (Eds.),...
  • Banerjee, A., 1996. Notes Towards a Theory of Industrialization in the Developing World. Mimeo,...
  • Banerjee, A., Munshi, K., 2000. Networks, Migration and Investment: Insiders and Outsiders in Tirupur’s Production...
  • Bardhan, P., 1984. Determinants of supply and demand for labor in a poor agrarian economy: an analysis of household...
  • Basant, R., 1994. Diversification of economic activities in rural Gujarat: some evidence at the micro level. In:...
  • Bell, C., Hazell, P., Slade, R., 1982. Project Evaluation in Regional Perspective. Johns Hopkins University Press for...
  • Burgess, R., 1997. Diversification and Welfare in Rural China. Mimeo, STICERD, London School of...
  • Byrd, W., Lin, Q., 1990. China’s rural industry: an introduction. In: Byrd, W., Lin, Q. (Eds.), China’s Rural Industry:...
  • Byrd, W., Zhui, N., 1990. Two market interactions and industrial structure. In: Byrd, W., Lin, Q. (Eds.), China’s Rural...
  • C.P. Chandrasekhar

    Agrarian change and occupational diversification: non-agricultural employment and rural development in West Bengal

    J. Peasant Stud.

    (1993)

  • Collier, P., Lal, D., 1986. Labor and Poverty in Kenya: 1900–1980. Clarendon Press,...
  • Dasgupta, P., 1993. An Inquiry into Well-Being and Destitution. Oxford University Press, New...
  • Datt, G., 1996. Bargaining Power, Wages and Employment: An Analysis of Agricultural Labor Markets in India. Sage, New...
  • De Janvry, A., Sadoulet, E., 1993. Rural development in Latin America: re-linking poverty reduction to growth. In:...
  • Drèze, J., Mukerjee, A., 1989. Labor contracts in rural India: theories and evidence. In: Chakravarty, S. (Ed.), The...
  • Du, H., 1990. Causes of rapid rural industrial development. In: Byrd, W., Lin, Q. (Eds.), China’s Rural Industry:...
  • Elbers, C., Lanjouw, P., 2001. Intersectoral transfer, growth and inequality in rural Ecuador, World Dev., in...
  • H. Evans

    A virtuous circle model of rural–urban development: evidence from a Kenyan small town and its hinterland

    J. Dev. Stud.

    (1992)

  • H. Evans et al.

    Rural–urban relations, household income diversification and agricultural productivity

    Dev. Change

    (1991)

  • Ferreira, F., Lanjouw, P., 2001. Poverty and Nonfarm Employment in Rural Brazil. World Dev. (in...
  • Government of India, 1992. Census of India 1991. Registrar General and Census Commissioner,...
  • Haggblade, S., Liedholm, C., Mead, D., 1986. The effect of policy and policy reforms on non-agricultural enterprises...
  • B. Harriss

    Regional growth linkages from agriculture

    J. Dev. Stud.

    (1987)

  • B. Harriss

    Regional growth linkages from agriculture and resource flows in non-farm economy

    Econ. Political Weekly

    (1987)

  • Harriss, B., Harriss, J., 1984. Generative or parasitic urbanism? Some observations from the recent history of a South...
  • G. Hart

    The growth linkages controversy. Some lessons from the Muda case

    J. Dev. Stud.

    (1989)

  • Hayami, Y. (Ed.), 1997. Toward the rural-based development of commerce and inquiry: selected experiences from East...
  • Hazell, P., Haggblade, S., 1990. Rural–urban growth linkages in India. PRE Working Paper Series No. 430. Agriculture...
  • Hazell, P., Roell, A., 1983. Rural growth linkages: household expenditure pattern in Malaysia and Nigeria. IFPRI Report...
  • Hazell, P., Ramasamy, C., Rajagopalan, V., Aiyasamy, P., Bliven, N., 1991a. Economic changes among village households....
  • Hazell, P., Ramasamy, C., Rajagopalan, V., 1991b. An analysis of the indirect effects of agricultural growth on the...
  • Hossain, M., 1984. Productivity and profitability in Bangladesh rural industries. Bangladesh Development Studies....
  • D. Hulme

    Can the Grameen Bank be replicated? Recent experiments in Malaysia, Malawi and Sri Lanka

    Dev. Policy Rev.

    (1990)

  • S. Hymer et al.

    A model of an Agrarian economy with non-agricultural activities

    Am. Econ. Rev.

    (1969)

  • IFPRI, 1985. International Food Policy Research Institute Report, 1984. IFPRI, Washington,...
  • Islam, R., 1987. Rural industrialization and employment in Asia: issues and evidence. In: Islam, R. (Ed.), Rural...
  • Johnston, B., Kilby, P., 1975. Agriculture and Structural Transformation: Economic Strategies in Late-Developing...
  • M. Kilkenny

    Rural/urban effects of terminating farm subsidies

    Am. J. Agric. Econ.

    (1993)

  • Cited by (276)

    • Nonfarm employment and consumption diversification in rural China

      2022, Economic Analysis and Policy

      With rapid growth and development, nonfarm employment has become an important source of livelihood for millions of rural households in China. Rural nonfarm employment is leading to an increase in income and consumption diversification, which has a direct implication on household well-being. Using Chinese General Social Survey 2017 data, this study explores the effects of nonfarm employment on Chinese rural households’ consumption diversification, measured by the Simpson index. We employ the endogenous treatment regression model and a synthesized instrumental variable to address the endogeneity of the nonfarm employment variable. Findings show that nonfarm employment increases consumption diversification significantly. We find heterogeneous effects of nonfarm employment between males and females and across geographical locations. In particular, our estimates show a higher level of consumption diversification is associated with nonfarm employment of female (relative to male) respondents and those residing in China’s eastern and western (relative to central) regions. Consumption diversification seems to monotonically increase with the increase in the household size and consumption expenditure quintiles. Further analysis reveals that nonfarm employment significantly increases household expenditures on food, culture and leisure activities, and online shopping.

    • What lessons Ethiopia could draw from China's township and village enterprises led rural industrialization? A thematic synthesis

      2022, Research in Globalization

      Despite managing rapid economic growth and demonstrating poverty reduction, Ethiopia did not achieve growth-enhancing rural transformation. A need to understand how to realize this can be obtained by synthesizing lessons from countries that have already attained it. In light of this, the purpose of the review was to carry out a thematic synthesis of China’s rural industrialization through the Township and Village Enterprises (TVEs) and generate context-specific lessons that can inform Ethiopia’s rural industrialization. Building on qualitative data management using the thematic synthesis approach, the review process involved extracting and coding data as well as developing, analyzing, and synthesizing themes from finally selected 46 peer-reviewed journal articles. The review and synthesis processes identified three major driving forces behind China’s growth miracle. These were policy drivers, entrepreneurial drivers, and sociocultural drivers. The finding showed that the driving forces were successfully held together with effective institutions as a core driving force to form a rural industrialization framework (RIF). The major lesson that could be drawn is China’s capability in building effective institutions. The RIF provides a holistic perspective in promoting the planning and implementation process of rural industrialization. Ethiopia can achieve successful rural industrialization and subsequent structural transformation by building and advancing effective formal and informal institutions with its own pragmatic, innovative, and sustainable means.

    • The impact of women's off-farm employment on depressive symptoms: Evidence from rural China

      2022, Social Science and Medicine

      While China's economy has grown rapidly in recent decades, urban-rural inequalities in mental health have persisted, and depression is more prevalent among rural women. Using a nationally-representative survey data in China, this paper investigates the impact of women's off-farm employment on their depressive symptoms. Results from instrumental variable and individual fixed effects estimation show that women's participation in off-farm employment leads to a significant reduction in depressive symptoms. We further take into account the confounding effects of working conditions, and the main results are robust. Moreover, off-farm employment enhances women's mental health mainly through pathways including increased absolute income, higher self-perceived relative income, more frequent healthy behaviors, increased likelihood of health investment, and obtaining more formal social support. Further evidence suggests that the depression-reducing effect of off-farm employment is more effective for those with more severe depressive symptoms, middle-aged and elderly persons, and women with lower body mass index. The findings have important implications for preventing depressive disorders and improving mental health in China and other developing countries.

    • Roles of rural non-farm employment (RNFE) in India: Why RNFE, the conveyor of a shock like COVID 19 is also the key to recovery?

      2022, Journal of Asian Economics

      We assess the role of Rural Non-Farm Employment (RNFE) in livelihoods and in likely impacts of shocks like COVID 19. In India’s agri-food system, the preponderance of small farmers with low endowments of human and financial capital implies that, RNFE has been the principal source of poverty reduction. Yet, RNFE is also the most adversely affected by shocks like COVID 19 and the measures adopted to prevent disease spread. To assess the roles of RNFE and possible effects of shocks, we uniquely utilize the recent rounds of nationally representative Periodic Labor Force Surveys (PLFS). To assess the “potential impact” of COVID 19 on workers, by using the large dataset, we match similar workers in different states of employment (SOE) where SOE may partly reflect the situation post shock. Job loss, reduction in work hours, movement across types of employment, casualization within RNFE is possible due to shocks to RNFE. We estimate that SOE in RNFE have significant association with poverty and income. With the data on COVID lockdown periods, we then validate the results to pair with the prospectively assessed impacts. Notwithstanding the effect of shocks, RNFE has the unique potential in recovery, being the prime rural income generator and risk mitigator apart from being characterized by comparatively high growth in female employment and in socially disadvantaged groups in India.

    • Land reallocation responses to China's New Rural Pension Scheme: Evidence from a regression discontinuity design

      2022, Journal of Rural Studies

      This study examines how labor reallocation has been associated with land reallocation following the implementation of the New Rural Pension Scheme (NRPS) in 2009. Based on data from the China Health and Retirement Longitudinal Survey (CHARLS) gathered during two periods (2013 and 2015), it uses the discrete changes generated by the new program's rules to identify the impact on land reallocation, as represented by the amount of land rented out by the elderly and their spouses. The age 60 NRPS eligibility threshold is associated with large increases in land rented out. The most important channel identified is the increase in the number of adult-children migrants, which reduces the number of farm workers and may help relax credit constraints. In contrast, the NRPS program has had no impact on the extent of elderly labor; there are no changes in their time spent caring for grandchildren or paid work in the labor market. A deeper examination of the welfare effect shows that despite labor and land reallocation, the NRPS has had no impact on either household consumption or elderly well-being. This study contributes to the literature by connecting land (as a factor of production) with the pension scheme, which may have policy implications regarding how money transfer programs would affect land and labor reallocation and individual welfare in other countries in the global context.

    • Household access to electricity and non-farm business in rural India: A panel data analysis

      2022, Energy for Sustainable Development

      The role of electricity in formation and performance of rural non-farm entrepreneurial ventures is widely debated. This study aims to understand how, in India, access to household electricity impacts rural households' decisions to take up entrepreneurial activities, operated within household premises. A panel dataset of nearly twenty thousand rural households carried out in the years 2004–05 and 2011–12 has been used to explore the impact of access to electricity on participation in rural non-farm enterprises using panel fixed-effects logit models. Further, the role of electricity access on earnings of non-farm enterprises is studied using Heckman two-stage selection models. It is concluded that electricity has a positive effect on the households' decision to establish non-farm enterprises operating within home premises. It is also found that, in the presence of the household electricity access, the income from business increases by 35.2% on an average. Upon extending the analysis to different groups of states, similar outcomes are observed for relatively rich states, states with relatively higher levels of rural electrification and states with relatively lower rates of rural electrification. In case of relatively poorer states, access to electricity enables a household to participate in the non-farm business sector but does not seem to have a statistically significant impact on their business income.

    View all citing articles on Scopus

    Recommended articles (6)

    • Research article

      A Propensity Score Matching Analysis of the Impact of Participation in Non-farm Enterprise Activities on Household Wellbeing in Rural Nigeria

      UMK Procedia, Volume 1, 2014, pp. 26-32

      The recent data of nationally representative sample of 3380 households from rural Nigeria was used to examine the effects of participation in non-farm enterprise activities on household wellbeing. The propensity score matching result shows that participation in nonfarm enterprise activities has a significant positive impact on household wellbeing by all measures. This suggests that non-farm enterprises could be a pathway for improving the wellbeing of rural households in developing countries.

    • Research article

      Conceptual Framework for Evaluating the Environmental Awareness and Eco-efficiency of SMEs

      Procedia CIRP, Volume 78, 2018, pp. 347-352

      Environmental problems are increasingly impacting society and nature. For this reason, companies are expected to become aware of the importance of seeking strategies and measures to mitigate and prevent environmental impacts. The growing concern about the availability of natural resources for future generations and their survival has been the premise for decision making in the industrial sector to improve the quality of life and preserve the environment. In this domain, important concepts such as sustainable development and eco-efficiency have been developed. They represent the trend to achieve a balanced use of resources and a reduction of environmental pollution by preventing waste and establishing economic returns. The aim of this paper is to present a conceptual framework for evaluating the eco-efficiency of small and medium-sized enterprise (SMEs) through four main factors: analysis, identification and evaluation, integration, and an action plan. As a result of the analysis, sustainability strategies are proposed to decrease the negative impact and increase the cost-effectiveness and the competitiveness of the SMEs.

    • Research article

      Evolution of land distribution in the context of development theories

      Land Use Policy, Volume 97, 2020, Article 104730

      Land distribution is the main core of economic development analysis. The main objectives of land distribution are the improvement of living standards in rural areas, redistribution of land by developing new land registration, redistributing income through job creation, and increasing the productivity of agricultural products. This paper discusses different land distribution programs and outlines the major demands for development theories. It delivers a review of land policies and rigorous case-studies evidence from a global perspective. It also presents a review of historical and sociopolitical literature to evaluate the trend of land distribution, agro-ecological potential of development theories, and various policy debates on land use. In addition, the paper provides a coherent review of case studies to analyze different development theories regarding the concept of land distribution. This paper concludes that development theories support multiple understandings of property rights, including community and policy debates regarding poverty alleviation in poor regions. Moreover, it conceptualized that development theories are urgently needed to prevent people from being driven out of their land. However, it is unlikely that land distribution is the most efficient policy and political framework in contexts. Therefore, traditional land distribution programs need to be revised considering development theories.

    • Research article

      Characteristics and driving factors of rural livelihood transition in the east coastal region of China: A case study of suburban Shanghai

      Journal of Rural Studies, Volume 43, 2016, pp. 145-158

      Based on data from 412 households, this study used the sustainable livelihoods approach to analyse changes in livelihood strategies and the relationship between those changes and rural household attitudes in an eastern coastal region of China. Focussing on household off-farm employment decisions and land transfer decisions, we classified the households into six types based on their livelihood strategies, namely, off-farm employment-oriented, balanced, off-farm, idle, professional, and conventional. The survey results indicate that two capital factors, age and education, and two mediating factors, wage and crop prices, are important influences of off-farm employment decisions, whereas factors such as policies and subsidies, machinery, activities organized by local agricultural cooperatives, and land rent substantially influence land transfer decisions. By analysing the characteristics, trends and driving factors of livelihood transitions, i.e., changes in rural household livelihood strategies, from 1993 to 2013, we explored the mechanisms of livelihood transitions. The results indicate that the proportion of conventional households decreased and the proportion of off-farm employment-oriented households and off-farm households increased. Agricultural production transformed from a system of scattered households (conventional and off-farm employment-oriented households) into broad-scale management households (professional and balanced households). These changes were the main characteristics of livelihood transitions under rapid industrialization combined with rapid urbanization in the Qingpu district. Rural livelihood transitions exhibited a stepped pattern, going through an initial stage, a self-organizing stage, and a government-led stage.

    • Research article

      Agriculture in the process of development: A micro-perspective

      World Development, Volume 129, 2020, Article 104888

      This paper compares national-level data from India with 40years of household panel data from rural India to track sectoral changes in employment and income as well as examine the hypothesis of induced innovation in agricultural production. In the national data, India appears to be in the midst of a structural transformation. The share of agriculture in GDP and employment has shrunk while agricultural output continues to grow. This productivity growth appears to adhere to the induced innovation hypothesis, as productivity per hectare has increased more rapidly than productivity per worker. Many of the same patterns exist in the household data. Tracking households across time, I observe agricultural output has increased, despite more households engaging in off-farm labor. Household agricultural production is highly specialized and has increased its reliance on improved inputs. However, while agricultural income has grown, industrial and service income has remained stagnant, and the relative income of these households has declined in recent years.

    • Research article

      Rural livelihood diversification and household well-being: Insights from Humla, Nepal

      Journal of Rural Studies, Volume 44, 2016, pp. 239-249

      Diversification of livelihoods is a commonly applied strategy for coping with economic and environmental shocks and instrumental in poverty reduction. In this paper, we have assessed the role of livelihood diversification in household well-being in Humla, a remote mountain district in west Nepal. Employing the data produced from household surveys, we developed a composite household well-being index incorporating four components and 15 indicators, and measured the effect of diversification on it. Results suggested a uniform pattern of diversification in terms of the number of activities undertaken for livelihoods but a highly varying degree of resultant well-being across households. Analysis showed that well-being was not associated with diversification per se but rather on a households' involvement in ‘high return sectors’ such as trade or salaried job. Because involvement in these remunerative sectors is determined by various financial, social and human capitals, poor households were unable to combat the entry barrier and were prevented from getting access to them. In this way, livelihood diversification was found to have a highly skewed effect leading to inequality of income and well-being. This, in turn, is likely to risk depriving the poor households from exploiting new economic opportunities even in the future.

    View full text

    Copyright © 2001 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved.

    The rural non-farm sector: issues and evidence from developing countries (2024)
    Top Articles
    Latest Posts
    Article information

    Author: Fredrick Kertzmann

    Last Updated:

    Views: 6011

    Rating: 4.6 / 5 (66 voted)

    Reviews: 89% of readers found this page helpful

    Author information

    Name: Fredrick Kertzmann

    Birthday: 2000-04-29

    Address: Apt. 203 613 Huels Gateway, Ralphtown, LA 40204

    Phone: +2135150832870

    Job: Regional Design Producer

    Hobby: Nordic skating, Lacemaking, Mountain biking, Rowing, Gardening, Water sports, role-playing games

    Introduction: My name is Fredrick Kertzmann, I am a gleaming, encouraging, inexpensive, thankful, tender, quaint, precious person who loves writing and wants to share my knowledge and understanding with you.